Options General Properties

Posted on March 22, 2015

Definitions

\[ (S(T) - X)^{+} - C_{E}e^{rT}\]

Put-call parity

Theorem For a stock that pays no dividends the following relation holds between the prices of European calls and put options, both with exercise price \(X\) and exercise time \(T\):

\[ C_E - P_E = S(0) - Xe^{-rT} \]

The above result can easily be shown using the no-arbitrage principle. By making an equivalence with the forward contracts, we can prove the following results:

\[ C_E - P_E = S(0) - d_0 - Xe^{-rT} \]

\[ C_E - P_E = S(0)e^{-r_dT} - Xe^{-rT} .\]

Theorem The prices of Americal put and call options with the same strike price \(X\) and expiry time \(T\) on a stock that pays no dividends satisfy

\[ S(0) - Xe^{-rT} \ge C_A - P_A \ge S(0) - X \]

Bounds on option prices

The following inequalities are obvious:

\[ C_E \le C_A, \qquad P_E \le P_A \]

One can also prove the following ones

\[ \begin{align*} C_E &< S(0) \\ S(0) - Xe^{-rT} &\le C_E \\ P_E &< Xe^{-rT} \\ -S(0)+Xe^{-rT} & \le P_E \end{align*}\]

For dividend paying stocks, the bounds are

\[ \begin{align*} \max\{0, S(0) - d_0 - Xe^{-rT}\} &\le C_E \le S(0) - d_0 \\ \max\{0, -S(0)+d_0+Xe^{-rT}\} &\le P_E < Xe^{-rT} \\ \end{align*}\]

European and American calls on Non-dividend paying stock

The prices of American and European call options on a stock that pays no dividends are equal, i.e., \(C_A = C_E\), whenever the strike price \(X\) and the expiry time \(T\) are same for both the options.

American options

One can easily show the following inequalities for American options that pays no dividends.

\[ \begin{align} (S(0)- Xe^{-rT})^{+} &\le C_A \le S(0) \\ (-S(0)+X)^{+} &\le P_A \le X \\ \end{align}\]

American options that pays dividends

The prices of American put and call options on a stock that pays no dividends satisfy the inequalities

\[ \begin{align} \max \{ 0, S(0) - d_0-Xe^{-rT}, S(0)-X \} &\le C_A < S(0)\\ \max \{0, -S(0) + d_0 + Xe^{-rT}, -S(0) + X \} &\le P_A < X \\ \end{align} \]

Variables that determine option prices

Here we shall analyze change of one variable keeping the other variables fixed.

European options

Strike price \(X\)

Asset price \(S\)

Here we consider the asset as a portfolio and make conclusions:

\[ \begin{align} C_E(S'') - C_E(S') &\le S'' - S' \\ P_E(S') - P_E(S') & \le S'' - S' \end{align} \]

American options

The relations of American options are more or less similar to that of European ones.

Strike price \(X\)

\[\begin{align} C_A(X') - C_A(X'') \le X'' - X'\\ P_A(X'') - P_A(X') \le X'' - X' \end{align}\]

Asset price \(S\)

\[ C_A(S'')- C_A(S') \le S'' - S' \\ P_A(S') - P_A(S) \le S'' - S'\]

Dependence on expiry time \(T\)

\[ \begin{align} C_A(T') &\le C_A(T''), \\ P_A(T') &\le P_A(T'') \end{align}\]

Time value of options

We use the following terminology. We say that at time \(t\) a call option with strike price \(X\) is

Similarly, we say that a put is:

The terms deep in the money and deep out of the money is used to say that the difference in the level is very high.

Intrinsic value: At time \(t\le T\), the intrinsic value of a call option with strike price \(X\) is equal to \((S(t)-X)^{+}\). The intrinsic value of a put option with the same strike price is \((X-S(t))^{+}\).

Time value: The time value of an option is the difference between the price of the option and its intrinsic value.

Proposition: For any European or American call or put option with strike price \(X\), the time value attains its maximum at \(S=X\).